ExergyFlow

Someone asserts they need to be microfounded. Someone claims they are not brand-new models. Someone rejected them or abandoned their ‘brand’ because they are no longer the cutting edge of heterodox economics. Perhaps these people are right. Perhaps it is me that is always late. Yet, I still reckon that stock-flow consistent (SFC) models are one of the most versatile theoretical tools we ‘dissenting’ macroeconomists have got. Needless to say, the SCF approach is not a new macroeconomic theory. Rather, it is a modelling methodology deeply grounded in the post-Keynesian paradigm in economics. It was pioneered by James Tobin (1982) and has been developed by Wynne Godley, Marc Lavoie, Gennaro Zezza, and other heterodox macro- and monetary-economists, ever since. In short, SFC economists base their models on sound social matrixes or accounting frameworks that integrate financial flows of funds with cross-sector balance sheets. These frameworks provide a consistency check mechanism for hypotheses, while reducing the degrees of freedom of theoretical models. In addition, they allow SFC modelers to shed light on the relations between economic sectors and between social classes (Dos Santos 2006). Finally, they account for real-world dynamics, as variables are modelled in such a way they move ‘forward non-ergodically in historic time’ (Godley & Lavoie 2007). As pointed out by Dos Santos (2005), the method adopted by SFC modelers is made up by three steps:
1. Do the ‘cross-sector’ accounting, i.e. set up both the nominal balance sheets and the transactions-flow matrix of the economy.
2. Derive the macroeconomic identities, set the equilibrium conditions, and choose the relevant behavioural relationships between macroeconomic variables (through a set of difference or differential equations).
3. Run computer simulations to see how the endogenous variables of the model react to shocks to exogenous variables and parameter values.
Two points are worth stressing. First, the SFC methodology logically leads to question the concept of ‘natural equilibrium’ underpinning mainstream macroeconomics models. For it allows modelling the transition from one dynamic time position to another, thereby recognising that ‘the conditions under which this transition occurs may affect the final position of equilibrium’ (Lavoie 2006). Second, the SFC approach could be applied to different economic views. In principle, it would be possible to depart significantly also from assumptions (and findings) of standard post-Keynesian models. In a sense, that is what we are going to discuss in Leeds on next Wednesday (see the flyer below).
All Welcome!

References & suggested readings

  • Caverzasi, E. & Godin, A. 2015. ‘Post-Keynesian stock-flow-consistent modelling: a survey.’ Cambridge Journal of Economics, 39 (1): 157-187.
  • Dos Santos, C. H. 2005. ‘A stock-flow consistent general framework for formal Minskyan analyses of closed economies.’ Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 27 (4): 711-735.
  • Dos Santos, C. H. 2006. ‘Keynesian theorising during hard times: stock-flow consistent models as an unexplored ‘frontier’ of Keynesian macroeconomics.’ Cambridge Journal of Economics, 30 (4): 541-565.
  • Dos Santos, C. H. & Zezza, G. 2008. ‘A Simplified,‘Benchmark’, Stock‐Flow Consistent Post‐Keynesian Growth Model.’ Metroeconomica, 59 (3): 441-478.
  • Godley, W. & Cripps, F. 1981. Macroeconomics. London: Fontana.
  • Godley, W. & Lavoie, M. 2007. Monetary economics: an integrated approach to credit, money, income, production and wealth. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
  • Lavoie, M. 2006. Introduction to Post-Keynesian Economics. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
  • Lavoie, M. 2008. ‘Financialisation issues in a Post-Keynesian stock-flow consistent model.’ Intervention: European Journal of Economics and Economic Policies, 5 (2): 331-356.
  • Sawyer, M. & Veronese Passarella, M. 2015. ‘The Monetary Circuit in the age of financialisation.’ Metroeconomica, doi: 10.1111/meca.12103.
  • Taylor, L. 2004. ‘Exchange rate indeterminacy in portfolio balance, Mundell–Fleming and uncovered interest rate parity models.’ Cambridge Journal of Economics, 28 (2): 205-227.
  • Tobin, J. 1982. ‘Money and finance in the macroeconomic process.’ Journal of money, credit and banking, 14 (2): 171-204.
  • Veronese Passarella, M. 2015. ‘Monetary Theories of Production’, in: T. Jo, L. Chester and C. D’Ippoliti (eds.), Handbook of Heterodox Economics, London: Routledge, forthcoming.
  • Zezza, G. 2012. ‘Godley and Graziani: Stock-Flow-Consistent Monetary Circuits,’ in: D. B. Papadimitriou and G. Zezza (eds.), Contributions in Stock-Flow Modeling: Essays in Honor of Wynne Godley. Basingstoke: Palgrave MacMillan, 154-172.

Flyer Aut 2015 (6)

 

Share on Socials:

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *